System Dynamics and Energy Modeling
[Bibliography]
The World Models
System
dynamics modeling has been used for strategic energy planning and
policy analysis for more than twenty-five years. The story begins with
the world modeling projects
conducted in the early 1970s by the System Dynamics Group at the
Massachusetts Institute of Technology. During these projects the WORLD2
and WORLD3
models were created to examine the "predicament of mankind" -- that is,
the long term socioeconomic interactions that cause, and ultimately
limit, the exponential growth of the world’s population and industrial output
.
One of the central assumptions underlying the world models is that the earth’s natural resources are, at some level, finite and that the exponential growth in their use could ultimately lead to their depletion and hence, to the overshoot and collapse of the world socioeconomic system. Due to the decision to explain the "predicament of mankind" with fairly small system dynamics models, the resource depletion dynamics were represented in the world models with structures that aggregated all of the earth’s natural resources into a single variable.
The decision to represent the earth’s natural
resources in aggregate form did not take place in a vacuum. As part of
the WORLD3 modeling project, several disaggregated,
resource-specific/issue-specific, models were created.
The conclusion drawn from these models was that it was appropriate to
lump all natural resources into a single variable in the WORLD3 model
.
The Life Cycle Theory of M. King Hubbert
One of the disaggregated, resource-specific, system
dynamics analyses that was conducted in support of the world modeling
efforts was a natural gas discovery and production model created by MIT
Master’s student Roger Naill.
Naill based his model on the life cycle theory of oil and gas discovery
and production put forth by petroleum geologist M. King Hubbert
.
In formulating his theory, Hubbert took the physical
structure of the fossil fuel system into account and assumed that the
total amount of oil and gas in the United States (i.e., the amount of
oil and gas "in place"), and hence the "ultimately recoverable" amount
of oil and gas in the United States, is finite.
As a result, according to Hubbert, the cumulative production of
domestic oil and gas must be less than or equal to the ultimately
recoverable amount of oil and gas in the United States
.
Figure 1 is a system dynamics stock-flow structure that represents Hubbert’s theory. The most important features of the structure are that (1) there is no inflow to the Ultimately_Recoverable stock (i.e., there is a fixed stock of oil and gas), and (2) the resource is being produced and consumed at an exponential rate.
Figure 1: Stock-Flow Structure Representing Hubbert’s View of Oil and Gas Discovery and Production
A direct implication of Hubbert’s theory is that a time series graph of either oil or gas production (at either the world-wide or domestic levels) must, at a minimum, be "hump" shaped. That is, the area beneath the production curve for oil or gas is the cumulative production of the resource, and the cumulative production of the resource must be a finite number. In fact, Hubbert argued that the life cycle of oil and gas discovery and production yields a bell-shaped production curve, which describes a period of low resource price and exponential growth in production, a peaking of production as the effects of resource depletion cause discoveries per foot of exploratory drilling to drop and resource price to rise, and a long period of rising costs and declining production as the substitution to alternative resources proceeds. Figure 2 shows a graphical representation of Hubbert’s life cycle theory of oil and gas discovery and production.
Figure 2: M. King Hubbert’s Life Cycle Theory of Oil and Gas Discovery and Production
Before proceeding, it is important to note that Hubbert’s view of natural resource discovery and production is not shared by all energy analysts. For example, Morris Adelman, a world-renowned resource economist (emeritus) at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, believes that there is no fixed stock of oil. Indeed, Adelman’s views vis-à-vis oil price and depletion were summarized in a 1991 column by Boston Globe reporter David Warsh:
Figure 3: Stock-Flow Structure Representing Adelman’s View of Oil and Gas Discovery and Production
Figure 3 is a system dynamics stock-flow structure representing Adelman’s view of oil and gas discovery and production. It is directly comparable to Figure 1. Two things about the figure are important to note. First, the cloud-like icon on the left side of the figure indicates that there is no limit to oil or gas discovery (i.e., there is no fixed stock of oil or gas). Second, two influences are battling each other for control of the Discovery_Rate: technological change and diminishing returns. Historically, technology has always defeated diminishing returns and Adelman, as well as many energy analysts, feels it will continue to do so.
Naill's Master's Thesis
The results of Roger Naill’s Master’s thesis study confirmed Hubbert’s life cycle hypothesis. Indeed, Naill concluded that the production of US domestic natural gas, which peaked in 1973, will continue to decline well below the US natural gas discovery rate until depletion halts all domestic production sometime in the late twentieth or early twenty-first century.
The results of Naill’s work brought to the forefront
the following question among the system dynamicists who were working on
energy modeling problems under the umbrella of the world modeling
programs: Will US economic growth be impeded by an energy limit similar
to those suggested in the Limits to Growth? To begin answering
this question, in 1972 the Resource Policy Group at Dartmouth College
received a three year contract from the National Science Foundation to
study the United States’ "energy transition problem."
The US Energy Transition Problem
The "energy transition problem" refers to the set of
disruptions that the US economy must go through as it reduces its
dependence on domestic gas and oil (due to depletion) and increases its
reliance on new sources of energy. Historically, the US economy has
gone through two energy transitions: (1) from wood to coal during the
late 1800s, and (2) from coal to oil and gas during the early 1900s.
But, these transitions were motivated by the availability of abundant
new energy sources that were cheaper and more productive than the
existing sources. The energy transition that the US is currently
facing, however, is being forced by depletion and rising production
costs, and not by a cheaper and more productive energy source.
The implications of the energy transition problem
for the United States are quite significant. The continued growth in US
energy demand, coupled with the depletion of domestic oil and gas
resources and long delays in the development of alternative domestic
energy sources is causing a widening domestic energy gap (domestic
energy demand - domestic energy supply). This gap can only be filled,
in the near term at least, through increased dependence on foreign
imports of natural gas and oil. In addition, as long as abundant oil
and gas imports are available at prices that are low relative to the
marginal cost of developing new domestic supplies (i.e., as long as
it’s easier to import oil and gas than it is to develop new domestic
energy sources), US oil and gas depletion will continue, if not
accelerate.
The COAL1, COAL2 and FOSSIL1 Models
Roger Naill’s natural gas model represented the US gas system at a very aggregate level. The model was not broken down by region, technology, or type of gas. It did not allow for the substitution of fuels nor for endogenous technological change. Thus, although it helped to motivate the study of the US energy transition problem, it was inadequate for the study itself. A new, expanded, model was required.
For his Ph.D. dissertation at Dartmouth, again under
the supervision of Dennis Meadows, Naill expanded the boundary of his
natural gas model to include all major US energy sources (energy
supply), as well as US energy consumption (energy demand).
He called his dissertation model COAL1, because his analysis showed
that the best fuel for the US to rely on during the energy transition
was coal
.
After he had completed his Ph.D., Naill worked with
the Dartmouth Resource Policy Group to improve and extend COAL1 as part
of the Group’s National Science Foundation grant activities. The
improved and extended version of the model was called COAL2.
In 1975, the Energy Research and Development Administration (which
later became the US Department of Energy) provided support to further
improve and extend COAL2 for use in government energy planning. This
improved and extended model was called FOSSIL1, since it looked at the
transition of an economy that is powered by fossil fuels (i.e., by oil,
gas, and coal) to one that is powered by alternative energy sources.
The FOSSIL1 model (as were its predecessors) was thus based on Hubbert’s theory of resource abundance, depletion, and substitution, and used to analyze and design new legislation that would enable the US economy to pass through the energy transition smoothly. It consisted of four main sectors: (1) energy demand, (2) oil and gas, (3) coal, and (4) electricity, and addressed, among others things, the following questions:
The results from using FOSSIL1 to analyze the energy transition questions were that:
The FOSSIL2 and IDEAS Models
In response to the United States’ first energy crisis in 1977, the Carter Administration created the first National Energy Plan. Shortly thereafter, the US House of Representatives asked the Dartmouth Resource Policy Group to evaluate the Plan using the FOSSIL1 model. After the evaluation of the Plan was completed, Roger Naill left the Resource Policy Group to head the Office of Analytical Services at the Department of Energy and, among other things, prepare energy projections in support of future National Energy Plans.
To prepare the energy projections for future
National Energy Plans, Naill implemented FOSSIL1 in-house at the
Department of Energy and supervised a team that extensively modified it
so that national energy policy issues could be analyzed. The modified
version of FOSSIL1 was called FOSSIL2.
From the late 1970s to the early 1990s, the FOSSIL2 model was used at the Department of Energy to analyze, among other things:
In 1989, the Congress directed DOE to conduct a study of energy technology and policy options aimed at mitigating greenhouse gas emissions. FOSSIL2 was used for this purpose. Some preliminary conclusions from the study were that:
In recent years, extensive improvements have been made to FOSSIL2’s transportation and electric utilities sectors.
The improved version of FOSSIL2 has been renamed IDEAS, which stands
for Integrated Dynamic Energy Analysis Simulation. The IDEAS model is
now maintained for the DOE by Applied Energy Services of Arlington,
Virginia
.
Sterman's Model of Energy-Economy Interactions
During the late 1970s John Sterman, an MIT Ph.D.
student and former Dartmouth College undergraduate, was hired by Roger
Naill to work with a team to modify and extend the FOSSIL1 model into
the FOSSIL2 model. During this work, Sterman came to realize that the
FOSSIL2 model ignored important feedbacks and interactions between the
energy sector of the economy and the economy itself. For his Ph.D.
dissertation, Sterman built a system dynamics energy model that
captured, for the first time, significant energy-economy interactions.
To be more precise, Sterman noticed that in the COAL-FOSSIL-IDEAS family of models, the energy sector is modeled in isolation from the rest of the economy. That is:
Sterman addressed these deficiencies through his modeling and found that:
Fiddaman's Model of Economy-Climate Interactions
Building on the work of his teachers, in 1997 Tom
Fiddaman submitted his Ph.D. dissertation on economy-climate
interactions to the Sloan School of Management at MIT.
The dissertation included a critique of existing (non system dynamics)
climate-economy models and a new climate-economy system dynamics model
called FREE (Feedback-Rich Energy Economy model). The FREE model
explicitly incorporates the dynamics of oil and gas depletion as a
"source constraint" on the energy-economy system (as do all of its
system dynamics predecessors), as well as the dynamics of a "sink
constraint" (i.e., climate change) on the energy-economy system. The
FREE model is the first energy-economy model of any kind to explicitly examine the impact of a source constraint on energy-economy interactions.
The FREE model also explores a number of feedback processes (e.g., endogenous technological change and bounded rational decision making with perception delays and biases) that have not been previously explored in a climate change context. In addition, it is constructed so that a particular parameterization will yield the results found in neoclassical (traditional) climate-economy models.
Estimating the Amount of Oil In-Place
In the early 1980s, system dynamicist George Richardson met a British petroleum analyst who claimed that the "amount of oil in the world is increasing." Richardson replied that, although world oil reserves may be increasing, or that the estimate of the amount of oil in the world may be increasing, the actual amount of oil in the world (the amount of oil in-place) is decreasing.
Richardson was unable to persuade the British petroleum analyst to change his mind, so he decided to build a system dynamics model that could demonstrate his point. He enlisted the assistance of John Sterman, who had recently finished his dissertation on energy-economy interactions and, as a starting point, turned to M. King Hubbert’s research and Roger Naill’s natural gas model.
Richardson and Sterman produced an oil exploration,
discovery, and production model that was similar in spirit to Naill’s
natural gas model, but that also had important extensions and
improvements. More precisely, their model allowed for endogenous
technological change and the substitution of synfuels for oil.
Richardson and Sterman first used their model to run
a synthetic data experiment that addressed the following question:
Which method of forecasting the world’s ultimately recoverable supply
of oil is more accurate, M. King Hubbert’s life cycle method or the
geological analogy method?
Since the world’s ultimately recoverable supply of oil is currently not
known, and cannot be known until all of the world’s oil has been
depleted, a synthetic data experiment was required to answer the
question.
The logic of Richardson and Sterman’s synthetic data experiment was quite simple. First build a system dynamics model that accurately replicates the exploration, discovery, and production behavior of the world oil system and assume that it is the "real world." Second, formally code and add the Hubbert and geologic analogy methods to the model so that they "watch" the "real world oil system" and create forecasts of the ultimately recoverable amount of oil in the "world." The results of the synthetic data experiment were that:
The implications of the geologic analogy method significantly overestimating the ultimately recoverable amount of oil in the world include:
Sterman and Richardson, with the assistance of
system dynamicist Pål Davidsen, went on to apply their model and
synthetic data technique to the question of the amount of ultimately
recoverable oil in the United States.
As in the case of world oil, Hubbert’s method was judged to be clearly
superior and the model was able to replicate US oil discovery and
production data extremely well. Of course, unlike the case of world
oil production which has not yet peaked, US domestic oil production (in
the lower 48 states) peaked in 1970. Since Hubbert had forecast in 1956
that US oil production (in the lower 48 states) would peak between the
years 1966 and 1971, his forecast is one of the most accurate and
remarkable in the history of energy forecasting
.
In light of this, Sterman, Richardson and Davidsen’s synthetic data
experiment for the United States is perhaps best interpreted as
supporting the argument that Hubbert’s method is the most accurate.
Other System Dynamics Modeling in the Oil and Gas Industry
System dynamics modeling has been used by numerous researchers, outside of the Naill-to-IDEAS lineage, to examine firm-level and industry-level issues in the oil and gas industry. Table 1 lists some of the work that has been done. Inspection of the table reveals that topics such as the behavior of OPEC and world oil markets, business process re-engineering in an oil and gas producing firm, international relations stemming from world oil supply and demand relationships, and oil firms as learning organizations, have been addressed with system dynamics. The Energy 2020 model was developed by George Backus and Jeff Amlin to provide individual energy firms and state agencies with a multi-fuel energy model. It is similar in design to the DOE’s IDEAS model.
Topic Area |
Authors |
Hubbert’s method versus the geologic analogy method |
Sterman and Richardson (1985); Sterman, Richardson and Davidsen (1988); Davidsen, Sterman and Richardson (1990) |
Hubbert’s Method applied to Mexico |
Duncan (1996a, 1996b) |
The behavior of OPEC and world oil markets |
Powell (1990a, 1990b); Morecroft (1992); Morecroft and van der Heijden (1992) |
Business process re-engineering in a gas and oil producing firm |
Genta and Sokol (1993) |
Shell Oil as a learning organization |
De Geus (1988) |
Learning about the oil industry from a management flight simulator |
Kreutzer, Kreutzer and Gould (1992); Morecroft (1992); Morecroft and van der Heijden (1992); Genta and Sokol (1993) |
International relations stemming from world oil supply and demand relationships |
Choucri (1981) |
Multi-fuel energy model for use by individual firms and state agencies |
Ford (1997, pp. 58-59) |
Table 1: Some Well-Known System Dynamics Studies in the Oil and Gas Industry
The efforts of oil companies to become "learning
organizations" through the use of "management flight simulators" is a
particularly noteworthy use of system dynamics in energy modeling. In
1990, system dynamicist Peter Senge wrote a book that outlined a way
for organizations to become "learning organizations" through the use of
system dynamics and other tools.
A learning organization is composed of employees who possess a shared,
holistic, and systemic vision, and have the commitment and capacity to
continually learn, rather than simply executing a "plan" put forth by the "grand strategist" at the top of the organization.
One of the principal tools used by learning organizations is the "management flight simulator." Management flight simulators are computerized learning environments that invite decision makers to train in a simulator just like a pilot does. The flight simulator runs an underlying system dynamics model for a number of periods, pauses, and waits for the decision maker to make a policy change. After the policy change has been entered, the flight simulator again simulates the model forward in time, pauses, and waits for the next policy change. After a decision maker has finished a session in the simulator, he or she is invited to determine why the system behaved as it did. Once the decision maker ascertains this, he or she is invited to play again. Of course, after a number of plays the decision maker’s understanding of the system should improve and, hopefully, he or she will apply the lessons learned to an actual organization.
System Dynamics Modeling in the Coal Industry
Applications of system dynamics outside of the Naill-to-IDEAS lineage also exist in the coal industry. As shown in Table 2, system dynamics has been used to study industry-level problems, mining systems, the dynamics of small surface coal operations, international mining ownership, and the representation of discrete events in system dynamics models.
Topic Area |
Authors |
The dynamics of small surface coal operations |
Kinek and Jambekar (1984a, 1984b, 1983) |
Industry-level studies |
Zahn (1981); Mendis, Rosenburg and Medville (1979) |
Mining systems |
Wolstenholme and Holmes (1985); Wolstenholme (1983, 1982b, 1981); Schwarz (1978) |
International mining ownership |
Wolstenholme (1984) |
Representing discrete events in system dynamics models |
Coyle (1985) |
Table 2: Some Well-Known System Dynamics Studies in the Coal Industry
System Dynamics Modeling in the Electric Power Industry
One of the studies that followed the world modeling
projects, was conducted by the Dartmouth Resource Policy Group and
undertaken in a fashion parallel to Roger Naill’s COAL1 study, was
Andrew Ford’s system dynamics analysis of the future of the US electric
power industry.
For his Ph.D. dissertation, Ford produced the ELECTRIC1 model, which
was the first in a series of system dynamics electric utility models
known as the EPPAM models
.
Modified versions of Ford’s model and its descendants were also used to
build the electricity sectors of the COAL2, FOSSIL1 and FOSSIL2 models
.
Since Ford’s pathbreaking work, system dynamics has been used extensively by utility managers for strategic planning.
Table 1 lists some well-known system dynamics studies that have
addressed problems in the electric power industry, including: the
effects of regulatory policy on utility performance, the "spiral of
impossibility," the effects of external agents on utility performance,
the financial performance of utilities, the effects of energy
conservation practices on utility performance, regional strategic
electricity/energy planning, national strategic electricity/energy
planning, electric vehicles, deregulation in the UK electric power
industry, deregulation in the US electric power industry, and river use
and its impact on hydroelectric power.
The system dynamics work on river use and its impact on hydroelectric power is particularly noteworthy as it involves the use of a management flight simulator in a public policy context. More precisely, the management flight simulator is designed to allow ordinary citizens, as well as utility managers and other stakeholders, to test policies aimed at moving hydroelectric systems in desired directions, while taking multiple criteria into account.
Topic Area |
Authors |
Effects of regulatory policy on utility performance |
Geraghty and Lyneis (1983) |
The "spiral of impossibility" |
Ford and Youngblood (1983). |
Effects of external agents on utility performance |
Geraghty and Lyneis (1985) |
Financial performance of utilities |
Lyneis (1985) |
Effects of energy conservation practices on utility performance |
Ford, Bull and Naill (1989); Ford and Bull (1989); Aslam and Saeed (1995) |
Regional strategic electricity/energy planning |
Dyner et al. (1990) |
National strategic electricity/energy planning |
Coyle and Rego (1983); Naill (1977, 1992); Sterman (1981) |
Electric vehicles |
Khalil and Radzicki (1996); Ford (1996b); Ford (1995a); Ford (1994) |
Deregulation in the UK electric power industry |
Bunn and Larsen (1992, 1994, 1995); Bunn, Larsen and Vlahos (1993); Larsen and Bunn (1994) |
Deregulation in the US electric power industry |
Lyneis, Bespolka and Tucker (1994) |
River use and its impact on hydroelectric power |
Ford (1996a) |
Table 3: Some Well-Known System Dynamics Studies in the Electric Power Industry
Summary: Intellectual Lineage of System Dynamics Energy Modeling
Figure 4 presents a diagram of the intellectual
lineage of system dynamics energy modeling. The lineage begins with the
first book on system dynamics modeling -- Industrial Dynamics by Jay W. Forrester.
Forrester’s original work spawned various firm and industry-level
system dynamics energy models and inspired Peter Senge to write the Fifth Discipline.
Senge’s book has led to the creation of energy-related management
flight simulators and several attempts at turning energy companies into
learning organizations.
Forrester was also responsible for creating the WORLD2 model and initiating the world modeling projects at MIT. The world models, along with M. King Hubbert’s work on oil and gas discovery and production, stimulated the creation of Roger Naill’s natural gas model, his COAL1 model, and the improvements to COAL1 that have culminated in the IDEAS model and its offshoots (FOSSIL79 and DEMAND81). Naill and Hubbert’s work formed the basis for Sterman, Richardson and Davidsen’s synthetic data experiments on analyzing techniques for forecasting the ultimately recoverable amount of oil in the world and in the United States, while knowledge of the weaknesses in the FOSSIL2 model caused Sterman to investigate the dynamics of energy-economy interactions during the energy transition. Fiddaman’s recognition that, although the source constraints on the energy-economy system had been investigated by energy modelers, sink constraints had not, lead to the creation of the FREE model. The world modeling projects also stimulated the study of the US electric power industry by Andrew Ford and the subsequent EPPAM models and their offshoots.
![]() ![]() |